Skip to content

Additional resources for earning interest in gold

5 responses to “What Causes Loss of Purchasing Power, Report 7 Apr”

  1. Thanks for the article, Keith,

    Another way to look at the problem is with orders of production. As the production of a good becomes more capital intensive, the number of steps involved, or orders of production, grows. In the normal case, each order of production is productive. However, in the case of regulations on milk production, these additional orders are unproductive.

    Regarding the what-a-dollar-is-worth question, recall that the dollar serves in this case as a medium of exchange–1 gal. milk = usd1. On the left side of the equation, a bunch of unproductive activities are attached to the gallon of milk; cost of production rises. So, it helps to identify which side of the equation is changing. Yet, this is difficult to do without careful analysis.

  2. Inflation really is a meaningless, garbage word. Thanks for pointing that out.

    Shouldn’t purchasing power, if it is to be measured at all, be measured in ounces of gold instead of USD? Then we can say something objective about gold as a store of value and also about whether it is increased cost of production due to regulation, or decreased cost of credit, that is causing some price (measured in gold) to rise. It seems like extra costs in production should also show up in the gold price.

    Looking at the reigning “king of commodities”, crude oil, who’s cost as an input to production is reflected in most other goods, we see that the gold price of crude since the Nixon default is a big nothingburger. Does that mean crude mining regulations remain static over time? Or at lease increase slow enough to be offset by mining productivity gains? I don’t know the whole story, but at least we can say gold has been as good a store of value as its “black gold” cousin.

  3. You mentioned the need for a word to cover the regulatory costs added to products, I think there may be one already: “regulatory burden”. An interesting pair of graphs would display the components of price into production costs and regulatory burden, and a second graph showing the regulatory burden costs additive through already burdened components – having that visually displayed might prove effective in showing how regulation ‘burdens’ an economy.

  4. Upon further reflection, the financial burden of regulations may show up as a type of one-time step up in cost as of the implementation date. After the initial increase in costs due to the new regulations, the long-term price trend could be assumed to continue, but only at a higher price level. An econometric study could reveal any regime changes or breaks in price that other variables do not account for.

    Secondly, cost does not necessarily equal price. An empirical study of elasticities and market power could reveal which party, the buyer or the seller, is absorbing the increased cost.

    Thus, the questions of what is the cause of and what is the timing of an increase in prices, regulations or monetary expansion, is an empirical one, and probably quite complex. Prices, therefore, may not be such a bad indicator of “price inflation” after all. This would have to be tested, though.

Leave a Reply

Want to join the discussion?

Feel free to contribute!

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

Gold Outlook Report 2025